Authors: Timothy H. Parsons
Tags: #Oxford University Press, #9780195304312, #Inc
self-determination, applied only to Nazi-occupied Europe, British
imperial subjects thought otherwise. Others concluded that an Axis
victory was their best hope for emancipation, and some West Indian
movie audiences cheered newsreels reporting Allied defeats. Similar sentiments prevailed in Asia, where more than thirty thousand
British
Kenya 333
Indian prisoners of war and deserters fought for the Japanese in Subhas Chandra Bose’s Indian National Army. In 1942 and 1943, India
itself experienced the worst outbreak of violent opposition since the
1857 mutiny when anti-imperial groups attacked post offi ces, train
stations, and other government installations. The Raj responded to
Gandhi’s even more damaging nonviolent Quit India movement by
jailing him and the rest of the Indian National Congress leadership.
There were no comparable outbreaks of violence in Kenya, but the
government took no chances and jailed the leaders of the Kikuyu
Central Association on the trumped-up charge of conspiring with the
Italians in Ethiopia.
These draconian measures bought the empire time, but the British government recognized that it would have to give its subjects a
stronger reason to support the Allied war effort. In 1942, Sir Stafford
Cripps, the leader of the House of Commons, offered the Indians full
dominion status or some alternative form of complete autonomy
within the British Commonwealth, which suggested an empire of
consent rather than coercion. One year later, the secretary of state
for the colonies made a broader pledge to guide all “colonial peoples
along the road to self-government within the framework of the British Empire.”50 Imperial offi cials tried to qualify and retreat from these
statements after the war, but there was no denying that peace would
bring signifi cant change to the empire.
This was apparent even in metropolitan Britain, where the Labour
Party’s victory in the 1945 elections testifi ed to a general weariness
with the war and the expense of empire. The British public wanted
rapid demobilization, jobs, heat, and housing, and most people were
unwilling to expend precious resources on retaining India or any other
imperial territory by force. While retreat from India would have been
unthinkable in the interwar era, these sentiments refl ected the reality
that Britain no longer profi ted from the Raj. Metropolitan manufacturers had already lost their share of Indian markets, and wartime
spending and borrowing meant that Britain actually owed India more
than one billion pounds in 1946. Acknowledging these realities, British offi cials hoped to guide India’s path to independence and shape its
postimperial government. Instead, violent sectarian civil strife resulting from irreconcilable differences between the Hindu and Muslim
communities forced Britain to withdraw its troops rapidly in 1947
and accept the partition of the Raj into India and Pakistan.
334 THE RULE OF EMPIRES
Most people in Britain recognized the necessity of Indian independence by this point, but the demise of the Raj gave imperial partisans an opening to make the case for retaining the rest of the empire.
As Cold War tensions mounted, the Labour foreign secretary Ernest
Bevin spoke of turning the remaining African and Asian territories
into a “third force” as a global counterbalance to the United States
and Soviet Union. More important, the economic problems of the
postwar era gave the Labour government a powerful incentive to try
once again to make the empire pay its promised dividends. Nearly six
years of total war left the nation with a debt approaching three billion pounds just as the United States ended its lend-lease program. In
what angry British offi cials termed a “fi nancial Dunkirk,” the American government forced Britain to ratify the Bretton Woods accord
and eliminate its imperial trade barriers as a condition for further
aid. Clement Attlee came to power on a platform of reconstruction,
economic development, and social reform, but his government lacked
the dollars to retire its debts and pay for imports of food and building
materials. As a result, the British public faced greater shortages and
deprivation in 1946 and 1947 than it had during the war years.
Many Britons therefore hoped that the imperial interests’ promises about the value of the African territories might hold true. Several
members of Attlee’s government had been strong critics of the imperial
excesses of the interwar years, but they believed that they could create
a more humane and mutually benefi cial system of imperial development now that they were in power. They assumed they could transform subject societies through central planning, mechanization, and
the 120 million pounds that an enhanced Colonial Development and
Welfare Act allocated for investment in the empire. Colonial secretary
Arthur Creech Jones, a onetime Fabian socialist, spoke optimistically
about raising living standards in the colonies, but the real purpose of
postwar colonial development was to earn dollars for Britain.
To this end the Labour government initiated an ambitious program of development in Africa that was channeled largely through
the new Colonial Development Corporation and other semioffi cial
enterprises. Blaming stunted African economies on the failure of free
market capitalism, the Labourites believed that rational economic
planning and state-sponsored investment could unlock the economic
potential of the remaining empire. One of their biggest and most
infamous projects was the sprawling Tanganyika groundnut scheme,
British
Kenya 335
which spent thirty-six million pounds planting peanuts on tracts of
land equal in size to the state of Connecticut. Similarly, a massive
irrigation program in the Sudanese al-Jazirah province aimed to produce vast quantities of cotton. The overall goal of these initiatives was
to provide raw materials that would reduce shortages in Britain and
earn dollars in North American markets.
To this end, state marketing boards bought African produce at
below-market prices on the promise that the banked surplus would
guarantee stable returns in good times and bad. Rising global
demand for commodities meant that there were no price downturns
in the immediate postwar era, thereby allowing the territorial governments to keep the African deposits in London, where they were
available for Britain’s postwar recovery. The returns from African
agriculture led the Colonial Offi ce’s development experts to meddle
even more deeply in local communities. Failing to realize that African farmers were already willing and able to produce for the global
market, their modernizing initiatives often alienated the very people
they aimed to help.
The Labour development initiative also did very little to actually
promote economic diversifi cation or industrial development in Africa.
In Kenya, the Colonial Development Corporation invested half a million pounds to turn a mix of improvised wartime industrial projects
into East African Industries Ltd. (EAL), a semipublic conglomerate
producing bricks, ceramics, tiles, chemicals, and cooking fats. These
were money-losing ventures, and Asian investors and entrepreneurs
had far more success in setting up small-scale industries that processed
locally produced raw materials. None of these enterprises, however,
altered Kenya’s neomercantile relationship with Britain, and restrictive investment and licensing regulations ensured that commodity
exports remained the central basis of the colony’s economy.
From 1945 to 1951, Britain put forty million pounds into the
empire, which was a fraction of the fi gure promised under the revised
Colonial Development and Welfare Act. Nevertheless, the Labour
government’s various programs netted 140 million pounds for the
metropolitan economy. This was in spite of debacles such as the Tanganyika groundnut scheme, which yielded only nine thousand tons of
produce—meaning that a pound of its peanuts cost more than seventeen hundred pounds.51 The resulting scandal almost brought down
the Labour government.
336 THE RULE OF EMPIRES
Most Africans, however, gave more than they got, and the Labourites’ promises of mutual development proved ephemeral. As in the
prewar era, British interests always came fi rst. Metropolitan buyers
had fi rst call on building materials for reconstruction, and the African territories had to reduce consumption to keep their dollar earnings within the empire. These policies led to shortages, infl ation, and
greater state interference in the daily lives of African workers and
farmers. The result was a wave of rural unrest and urban strikes that
swept through British Africa in the postwar years. Most were over
low wages and commodity prices, but the imperial authorities gradually recognized that they had the potential to mushroom into organized political resistance to British rule.
The Labour government’s imperial experts naively believed that
they could defuse this discontent by granting Africans a measure of
local autonomy and reforming the most fl agrantly abusive legal and
social institutions. Certain that “the natives” were not ready for full
independence, they promised to put their subjects on a gradual path
to self-government. Creech Jones sought to replace indirect rule
with a democratic system of local administration to bind educated
Africans more closely to the imperial regime. Theoretically, qualifi ed
men would move from elected local bodies to seats on territorial legislative councils, which in time might become national parliaments
as the colonies and protectorates evolved into autonomous entities
within the Commonwealth. In the meantime, the Colonial Offi ce
directed district offi cers to be scrupulously courteous in their dayto-day dealings with African constituents and began to retire old
Africa hands who, in the words of a new Colonial Service handbook,
tended to like “primitive people but could not get on well with the
educated native.”52
Not surprisingly, none of these developments sat well with the
Kenyan government or settlers. The old Africa hands remained
fi rmly entrenched in the colony, and the postwar governor Sir Philip
Mitchell believed that Kenya should develop along Rhodesian lines
into a self-governing dominion. He consequently continued his predecessors’ policies of encouraging additional settlement in the white
highlands. As a result, migration spiked in the postwar era as a new
generation of settlers swelled the European population of the colony
to thirty thousand on the premise that it would continue to be a white
man’s country.
British
Kenya 337
Governor Mitchell shared this assumption. Seeking to lay the
groundwork for a potential East African dominion, in 1946 he implemented a new legislative system that replaced his Executive Council
with an “elected member system.” This gave settler leaders control of
key government departments, which evolved into formal ministries.
Thus, Major Ferdinand Cavendish-Bentinck, the informal head of the
postwar settler community, acquired the important portfolio for agriculture, animal husbandry and natural resources. By comparison, a
former schoolteacher named Eliud Mathu became the sole appointed
African representative in the lower Legislative Council until three
more nominated African councilors joined him later in the decade.
On the surface, these measures appeared to make the Kenyan
imperial regime more secure than ever. Population growth in the
reserves ensured that employers had no diffi culty recruiting African
workers at comfortably low wages. Wartime profi teering gave the
settler farmers the resources to invest in tractors and other forms of
mechanization, which made them far less reliant on squatter labor.
Able to dispense with the old imperial tools of labor extraction, they
now sought to wall themselves off from all Africans but their domestic servants. Under settler pressure, sympathetic government offi cials
resumed the mandatory relocations of the 1930s and forcibly returned
roughly one hundred thousand squatters to the Kikuyu reserves
between 1945 and 1952. These rural slums were no less crowded than
they had been in the interwar era, but agricultural and social welfare
experts hoped to develop them though soil conservation measures
and modern agricultural technologies so that they could hold more
people. This was entirely unrealistic, but it provided political cover
for the Kenyan government’s pro-settler policies.
The Labour government’s mandate to end overt racism in the
empire made this window dressing necessary. In 1948, the Colonial Offi ce ordered the colonial governors to produce confi dential
memorandums justifying legislation in their territories that might
be viewed as discriminatory. Mitchell’s report was telling. While it
boasted that Kenya had increased direct African representation on
the Legislative Council, reformed the
kipande
system, and allowed
lawful marriage between Africans and Europeans, it stoutly defended
legal segregation in the colony on the basis of unequal “civilization.” Arguing that the British government’s earlier declarations in