Authors: Timothy H. Parsons
Tags: #Oxford University Press, #9780195304312, #Inc
Africa). Africans in the other two territories saw this as a bid by
the Kenyan settlers for control of the entire East African highlands.
“Natives” had no voice in high imperial policy, but the Ugandans
and Tanganyikans were fortunate that the plan fl oundered with the
depression.
Realistically, the imperial special interests were in no position to
sustain an East African Federation. Large plantations on the coast
brought the Kenyan government some revenue through export tariffs, but the neomercantilist nature of the new imperialism effectively
ruled out industrial development in the colony. The Colonial Offi ce
blocked a bid by Asian entrepreneurs to build a textile mill, to ensure
it did not compete with metropolitan weavers, and most manufac-318 THE RULE OF EMPIRES
turing enterprises involved the production of soap, fl our, fats, jam,
tobacco, and beer for local consumption. The Magadi Soda Ash Company, which was Kenya’s only viable export industry, needed a subsidized railway branch line simply to stay in business. In many years
the metropolitan Treasury had to help balance the colony’s budget,
which demonstrated that the British government had made a particularly poor investment in choosing the settlers to drive Kenya’s
economic development. Most were inept farmers who spent most of
their income on creature comforts instead of improving production.
They depended on short-term loans to fi nance future plantings but
had diffi culty establishing good credit because speculation drove the
value of their land beyond its actual capacity.
High production costs meant that the settlers needed protective
tariffs, reduced railway rates, and extremely cheap labor to remain
competitive. Securing abundant supplies of African labor was the
most viable of the three strategies, for the Congo Basin Treaty limited
the Kenyan government’s ability to restrict trade. Furthermore, the
Uganda government refused to pay higher freight costs on imports
to subsidize Kenyan exports. The settlers therefore returned to the
prewar strategy of trying to turn their political infl uence to extractive ends. In addition to demanding government assistance in labor
recruiting, they also wanted higher African taxes, restrictive employment laws, and permission to forcibly discipline their workers.
While the Kenyan imperial authorities were sympathetic, coerced
labor in any form was politically indefensible in interwar Britain.
In 1919, settler leaders convinced Governor Sir Edward Northey to
issue a series of circular orders directing district offi cers to “exercise
every possible lawful infl uence” in pushing African men, women, and
even children to “come out into the labour fi eld.” The fi rst and most
controversial circular warned that the government would have to
resort to “special methods” if particular communities did not produce
suffi cient numbers of workers. Intense metropolitan criticism forced
Northey to issue a follow-up order clarifying that he did not expect
government offi cials to recruit labor directly for private employers.
Instead he increased the African poll tax from ten shillings to sixteen and pointed out that while “no actual force can be employed to
compel a man to go out to work, he can, however, be made to pay his
tax.” The unspoken assumption in this statement was that defaulters
would work for the settlers. Finally, the governor took the particularly
British
Kenya 319
controversial step of making wage labor a greater priority than work
on African peasant farms, which raised the risk of famine in many
communities.39 Northey, who, as a native-born South African, was
particularly sympathetic to settler interests, was uncompromising in
removing district offi cers who balked at implementing the circulars.
The Conservative imperial enthusiast Leopold Amery defended
Northey’s actions in Parliament by claiming that they would save
East Africans from dying out like the Amerindians and Polynesians.
This argument carried little weight with the humanitarian lobby.
While this coalition of missionaries, antislavery activists, liberal civil
servants, and socialists generally agreed with Northey that Africans
should work, they absolutely rejected the concept of forced labor.
Frank Weston, the Anglican bishop of Zanzibar, was one of the most
uncompromising critics, and his scathing attack on the Kenyan labor
policies entitled
The Serfs of Great Britain
helped push the Colonial
Offi ce to order Northey to issue a new circular spelling out greater
protections for African laborers.
The Kenyan authorities had better luck defending the Registration
of Natives Ordinance, which required all African men and boys over
the age of fi fteen to carry a special labor passport, known as a
kipande
(piece, slip) in Swahili, that recorded their fi ngerprints, tribal origins,
biographical data, and employment record. Carried in a metal case
worn around the neck, the
kipande
was one of the great innovations
in the history of empire. For once, an imperial power had a viable way
to keep track of rural people, and the
kipande
made it much harder
for individuals to resist or evade oppressive policies by blending into
a nameless subject majority. Men traveling outside their reserves
had to supply it to any policeman or district offi cer on demand, and
the chief registrar of natives kept a duplicate copy of each certifi cate,
thereby making it possible to identify a man by his fi ngerprints.
Most signifi cant, the system kept wages down because workers
could not fi nd a new job unless their previous employer signed off
on their
kipande
. The most abusive settlers kept their laborers in virtual bondage by refusing to do so. Men who broke their contracts
faced legal sanction, and the government made it easy for employers to prosecute them with a “Complaint of Desertion of Registered
Native” form. The Kenyan authorities issued more than one million
labor registration certifi cates by the end of the 1920s and charged
roughly ten thousand men per year with
kipande
violations. Those
320 THE RULE OF EMPIRES
who destroyed or tried to forge the certifi cates faced stiff fi nes and
three months in jail.
Africans, understandably, detested the system. They found the
fi ngerprinting demeaning and compared the metal
kipande
case and
neck strap to a dog collar. Harry Thuku, a mission-educated telephone
operator, fanned this widespread anger to organize the fi rst mass
African political resistance to imperial rule. Using popular discontent
over wage cuts, high taxes, settler land seizures, and most particularly
the
kipande
system as catalysts, he founded the East Africa Association (EAA) in 1921. The Association claimed to be nonpolitical, but
it challenged the government’s unqualifi ed support for the settlers.
Thuku audaciously held public meetings where women and girls
recounted rapes on settler farms, and he called on people to turn in
their
kipandes
en masse for delivery to the governor. The authorities found this sort of organized opposition intolerable. In 1922, the
Kenyan police arrested Thuku for subversion and forcibly broke up a
crowd that gathered to demand his release. In doing so they injured
twenty-fi ve and killed Mary Nyanjiru. By all accounts, she was of
common origins, but her death and the mass protest forced the government to reduce the poll tax from sixteen shillings to twelve and
address some of the worst labor abuses. However, the imperial regime
refused to acknowledge that it had bowed to African pressure, and
it tried to cover up the riot and Mary Nyanjiru’s death by exiling
Thuku and shutting down his association.
Banning the EAA appeared to smother the
kipande
protests, but
the Kenyan authorities did not understand that simmering tensions
in the countryside were the greatest threat to British rule. By the
1920s, many of the twenty-four separate native reserves, which covered more than forty-six thousand square miles, had become considerably overcrowded and eroded. With average population growth
rates ranging from 1 to 2 percent per year, it was only a matter of
time before they lost the capacity to support subsistence agriculture.
Conditions were most severe in the three Kikuyu districts of Nyeri,
Kiambu, and Fort Hall (Murang’a), where population densities of
roughly 280 people per square mile forced up to three-quarters of the
able-bodied men in some localities to leave home in search of work.
The strain was almost as intense in the densely populated Luo and
Luhya reserves in western Kenya, where between one-quarter and
one-half of the adult men also became labor migrants.40 Population
British
Kenya 321
pressure, land shortages, commercialized agriculture, and class formation were far more effective than the Northey circulars in forcing
poorer Africans to work.
Many of these people, however, went to Nairobi, Mombasa, and
corporate plantations instead of the white highlands. Unable to offer
decent wages, the settlers had to court laborers by giving them permission to raise their own crops and cattle on the vast unused portions of their farms. Under Kenyan law, these were supposed to be
contract workers, but by 1930 there were approximately 120,000 of
these “squatters” permanently occupying 20 percent of the land in the
highlands. Ironically, some were working land that had belonged to
their families in the preconquest era. This squatter system was cheap
but ineffi cient. Exploiting African peasant production was hardly a
mark of progressive agricultural development, and the settler farm
was more of a “feudal estate” than a capitalist enterprise.41
Seeking greater dignity and autonomy, some landless people
understandably preferred “trespassing” in the native reserves of other
tribes to squatting or working for Europeans. This illegal migration
had the added benefi t of providing an escape from chiefl y supervision
and taxation. In effect, it was a way to cease being a tribesman. For the
Kikuyu, the nearby Maasai reserve was a tempting destination. Covering almost fi fteen thousand square miles of prime agricultural land,
it had a population density of just three people per square mile. The
approximately forty thousand Maasai held title to such a vast swath
of territory by virtue of a pair of treaties with the IBEAC that were a
legacy of their participation in the conquest of the highlands.42 These
treaties barred the Kenyan government from redrawing their tribal
boundaries to relieve population pressure in the most overcrowded
regions on either side of the Rift Valley. District offi cers were legally
bound to send interlopers back to their reserves, where they had little
chance of competing with the chiefs and mission school graduates
who had already appropriated the best land.
Although they were the privileged elite of the reserves, these
chiefl y and educated intermediaries also disliked being treated like
imperial subjects and bitterly resented the settlers’ dominance of the
white highlands. In 1925, a more aggressive younger generation of
Kikuyu took control of Thuku’s East Africa Association and transformed it into the Kikuyu Central Association (KCA). Although
the chiefs tended to distrust the mission-educated men of the KCA,
322 THE RULE OF EMPIRES
almost every Kikuyu shared a deep antipathy toward the reserve system. For this reason, many of the imperial regime’s most important
allies quietly backed the association’s decision to send Jomo Kenyatta
to London in 1929 to petition the British Parliament for relief from
oppressive land and labor policies.
The metropolitan authorities refused to even consider the KCA’s
appeal on the technicality that it did not come through the Kenyan
government. Nevertheless, pressure from the humanitarian lobby
forced the Colonial Offi ce to create a special commission to investigate Kenya’s ethnically based land policies. Although British offi cials
had no sympathy for the KCA, the environmental degradation of
the North American dust bowl and rapid African population growth
raised the prospect that the agricultural foundation of the tribal economies might collapse, thereby rendering the entire system of indirect
rule unsustainable. The Kenya Land Commission’s main concern was
to protect the settlers’ claim to the highlands by repairing the native
reserve system. Its report ruled that the reserves were suffi cient for
the needs of Kenya’s tribes, but it recommended an ambitious conservation and development program to increase the carrying capacity
of African land. Acknowledging the growing African land hunger, the
commissioners called only for a small revision of the tribal boundaries as well as opening some marginal parts of the forest reserves for
African settlement.
In defending the racial and ethnic division of land in the colony,
the Land Commission gave the government sanction to begin expelling surplus squatters from the highlands. While they needed some
Africans to work their land, by the 1930s the settlers were growing increasingly anxious about the size of squatter families on their