The Downing Street Years (127 page)

Read The Downing Street Years Online

Authors: Margaret Thatcher

BOOK: The Downing Street Years
4.38Mb size Format: txt, pdf, ePub

I also met M. Rocard, the new Socialist Prime Minister. I had met him before but did not know him well. He spoke disarmingly and I felt sincerely about his affection for Britain and the special understanding — inherited from wartime — between the two countries. As French Socialists go, he was moderate, pragmatic and sensible and I warmed to him. I hoped that he might come to exercise some moderating influence on France’s flirtation with European federalism.

On Saturday 18 June 1988 I flew to Toronto for the G7 economic summit. President Mitterrand had suggested optimistically to me in Paris that this being President Reagan’s last summit there might be an inclination to put off difficult decisions. I had replied that I did not think this likely and, for my part, I was determined to ensure that we used this occasion to get to grips with agriculture and the GATT. By the time I reached Toronto I had done my homework on the subject. In particular, we had devised a mythical beast known informally as ‘Howe’s Cow’ or more precisely as a ‘Producer Subsidy Equivalent’. This was the calculation of how much agricultural support, whether in direct subsidy or from protection, each country provided, divided by the number of cows. The greediest cow turned out to be Japan’s — so not surprisingly, the Japanese, with some support from the Americans, disputed our statistical approach.

I was, therefore, well armed with useful facts and figures when Brian Mulroney, the summit chairman, asked me to open the economic discussion on the Sunday afternoon. I drew attention to the success
of the current second cycle of summits, now ending, compared with the first. We had seen economic growth, low inflation and more jobs in the years since the Montebello summit in 1981, because we had stuck to getting the fundamentals right rather than concentrating on demand management. But there was more to do. Above all, we must fight down protectionism. I strongly urged — and repeated in a further intervention the following day — that all of us should honour the commitments made at the start of the GATT Uruguay round in September 1986 by coming up with firm proposals at the forthcoming ‘Medium Term Review’ meeting of the GATT.

As the dispute over measuring agricultural subsidies exemplified, free trade is something which almost everyone subscribes to in principle and finds politically painful in practice. Britain always had everything to gain from a global open trading system. The United States too traditionally believed in free trade. But Britain’s own trade policy was now in the hands of the Community, which contained a majority of countries with a tradition of cartels and corporatism and a politically influential agricultural sector. We were in a minority in Europe when it came to deciding trade policy. As for the United States, its huge trade deficit had given a protectionist turn to policy which President Reagan, a convinced free trader, found difficulty resisting. For its part, Japan not only subsidized and protected its agriculture more than anyone else; it also continued to place obstacles in the way of foreign imports of nonagricultural goods and services. Consequently, I increasingly had to look to the ‘Cairns Group’ of fourteen countries (which includes Canada, Australia, and Argentina) and to Third World countries, anxious to export their agriculture and textiles, to bring pressure on this wealthy western protection racket. I always regarded free trade as far more important than all the other ambitious and often counter-productive strategies of global economic policy — for example the policies of ‘co-ordinated growth’ which led principally to inflation. Free trade provided a means not only for poorer countries to earn foreign currency and increase their peoples’ standards of living. It was also a force for peace, freedom and political decentralization: peace, because economic links between nations reinforce mutual understanding with mutual interest; freedom, because trade between individuals bypasses the apparatus of the state and disperses power to customers not planners; political decentralization, because the size of the political unit is not dictated by the size of the market and vice versa.

After some two and a half hours of discussion on this subject at Toronto we achieved a broadly satisfactory communiqué. It reaffirmed
the Uruguay round commitments and underlined the importance of its ‘Medium Term Meeting’, while avoiding inclusion of what seemed to me the unrealistic United States objective of no agricultural subsidies by the year 2000. What remained to be seen was how the GATT negotiations now actually evolved. Had I been an optimist I might have drawn comfort from the fact that Toronto was the first time that M. Delors praised one of my speeches. But I kept my optimism in check.

DISCUSSION OF EMU

At Toronto I had an hour’s meeting with Chancellor Kohl. Much of it focused on the forthcoming Hanover summit. Chancellor Kohl, supported by the German Finance Ministry and the Bundesbank, seemed ready now to plump for a committee of central bankers rather than academic experts — as the French and Hans-Dietrich Genscher wanted — to report on EMU. This I welcomed. But I restated my unbending hostility to setting up a European Central Bank. By now I was having to recognize that the chance of stopping the committee being set up at all was ebbing away; but I was determined to try to minimize the harm it would do. I also had to recognize that we were saddled with M. Delors as President of the Commission for another two years, since my own favoured candidate, Ruud Lubbers, was not going to stand and the French and Germans supported M. Delors. (In the end I bit the bullet and seconded M. Delors’s reappointment myself.)

The Hanover Council turned out to be a fairly good-humoured if disputatious affair. The most important discussion took place on the first evening over dinner. Jacques Delors introduced the discussion of EMU. Chancellor Kohl suggested that a committee of Central Bank governors with a few outsiders be set up under M. Delors’s chairmanship. In the ensuing discussion most of the heads of government wanted the report to centre on a European Central Bank. Poul Schlüter opposed this and I supported him strongly, quoting from an excellent article by Karl Otto Pöhl, the President of the Bundesbank, to illustrate all the difficulties in the way of such an institution. We succeeded in getting mention of the Central Bank removed. But otherwise there was nothing I could do to stop the committee being set up. The Delors Group was to report back to the June 1989 European Council — that is in a year’s time. I hoped that the Governor of the Bank of England
and the sceptical Herr Pöhl would manage to put a spoke in the wheel of this particular vehicle of European integration; unfortunately, as I have already explained, that was not to be.

My problem throughout these discussions of EMU was twofold. First, of course, was the fact that I had so few allies; only Denmark, a small country with plenty of spirit but less weight, was with me. But I was fighting with one hand tied behind my back for another reason. As a ‘future member’ of the EEC, the UK had agreed a communiqué in Paris following a conference of heads of government in October 1972. This reaffirmed ‘the resolve of the member states of the enlarged Community to move irrevocably [towards] Economic and Monetary Union, by confirming all the details of the acts passed by the Council and by the member states’ representatives on 22 March 1971 and 21 March 1972’. Such language may have reflected Ted Heath’s wishes. It certainly did not reflect mine. But there was no point in picking a quarrel which we would have lost. So I preferred to let sleeping dogs lie.

Then, of course, they woke up and started barking in the course of the negotiation of the Single European Act of 1985–6.1 had not wanted any reference to EMU in at all. The Germans failed to support me and so the reference to EMU was inserted. But I had Article 20 of the Single European Act give my interpretation of what EMU meant; its title read: ‘Co-operation in Economic and Monetary Policy (Economic and Monetary Union)’. This enabled me to claim at subsequent forums that EMU now meant economic and monetary co-operation, not moving towards a single currency. There was a studied ambiguity about all this. Councils at Hanover in June 1988 and then at Madrid in 1989 referred back to the Single European Act’s ‘objective of progressive realization of economic and monetary union’. I was more or less happy with this, because it meant no more than co-operation. The rest of the European heads of government were equally happy, because they interpreted it as progress towards a European Central Bank and a single currency. But at some point, of course, these two interpretations would clash. And when they did I was bound to be fighting on ground not of my choosing.

For the fact was that the more I saw of how the Community operated the less I was attracted by any further steps on the road towards monetary integration. We advanced our proposals for a ‘hard ecu’. We issued Treasury bills denominated in ecu terms. And (though this was done because it was in our own interests, not in order to please our European partners) we had swept away exchange controls before anyone else. All this was very
communautaire
in its way, as I never
ceased to point out when criticized for resisting entry into the ERM. But my own preference was always for open markets, floating exchange rates and strong political and economic transatlantic links. In arguing for that alternative approach I was bound to be handicapped by the formal commitment to European ‘economic and monetary union’ — or indeed that of ‘ever closer union’ contained in the preamble to the original Treaty of Rome. These phrases predetermined many decisions which we thought we had reserved for future consideration. This gave a psychological advantage to my opponents, who never let an opportunity go by of making use of it.

THE BRUGES SPEECH

Not the least of those opponents was Jacques Delors. By the summer of 1988 he had altogether slipped his leash as a
fonctionnaire
and become a fully fledged political spokesman for federalism. The blurring of the roles of civil servants and elected representatives was more in the continental tradition than in ours. It proceeded from the widespread distrust which their voters had for politicians in countries like France and Italy. That same distrust also fuelled the federalist express. If you have no real confidence in the political system or political leaders of your own country you are bound to be more tolerant of foreigners of manifest intelligence, ability and integrity like M. Delors telling you how to run your affairs. Or to put it more bluntly, if I were an Italian I might prefer rule from Brussels too. But the mood in Britain was different. I sensed it. More than that, I shared it and I decided that the time had come to strike out against what I saw as the erosion of democracy by centralization and bureaucracy, and to set out an alternative view of Europe’s future.

It was high time. It was clear that the momentum towards full blooded EMU, which I always recognized must mean political union too, was building. In July M. Delors told the European Parliament that ‘we are not going to manage to take all the decisions needed between now and 1995 unless we see the beginnings of European government in one form or another,’ and predicted that within ten years the Community would be the source of ‘80 per cent of our economic legislation and perhaps even our fiscal and social legislation as well’. In September he addressed the TUC in Bournemouth calling for measures to be taken on collective bargaining at the European level.

But there were also more subtle, less easily detectable, but perhaps even more important signs of the way things were going. That summer I commissioned a paper from officials which spelt out in precise detail how the Commission was pushing forward the frontiers of its ‘competence’ into new areas — culture, education, health and social security. It used a whole range of techniques. It set up ‘advisory committees’ whose membership was neither appointed by, nor answerable to, member states and which tended therefore to reach
communautaire
decisions. It carefully built up a library of declaratory language, largely drawn from the sort of vacuous nonsense which found its way into Council conclusions, in order to justify subsequent proposals. It used a special budgetary procedure, known as
‘actions ponctuelles’
which enabled it to finance new projects without a legal base for doing so. But, most seriously of all, it consistently misemployed treaty articles requiring only a qualified majority to issue directives which it could not pass under articles which required unanimity.

Often, as over the environment, or later on health and hours of work, it was difficult to explain to the general public precisely why we opposed the specific measure the Commission wanted. When commissioners issued directives outside their competence they were careful to choose popular causes which had support among pressure groups in member countries, thus presenting themselves as the true friends of the British worker, pensioner and environmentalist. This made it politically difficult to resist the creeping expansion of the Commission’s authority. In theory, it would have been possible to fight all this in the courts; for time after time the Commission were twisting the words and intentions of the European Council to its own ends. We did indeed fight, and won a number of cases on these grounds before the European Court of Justice (ECJ). But the advice from the lawyers was that in relation to questions of Community and Commission competence the ECJ would favour ‘dynamic and expansive’ interpretations of the treaty over restrictive ones. The dice were loaded against us.

The more I considered all this, the greater my frustration and the deeper my anger became. Were British democracy, parliamentary sovereignty, the common law, our traditional sense of fairness, our ability to run our own affairs in our own way to be subordinated to the demands of a remote European bureaucracy, resting on very different traditions? I had by now heard about as much of the European ‘ideal’ as I could take; I suspected that many others had too. In the name of this ideal, waste, corruption and abuse of power were reaching levels which no one who supported, as I had done, entry to the European Economic Community could have foreseen. Because Britain was the
most stable and developed democracy in Europe we had perhaps most to lose from these developments. But Frenchmen who wanted to see France free to decide her own destiny would be losers too. So would Germans, who wished to retain their own currency, the deutschmark, which they had made the most credible in the world.

Other books

The Outcast Blade by Jon Courtenay Grimwood
In the Midnight Rain by Barbara Samuel, Ruth Wind
Love Unbound by Evelyn Adams
Island Intrigue by Wendy Howell Mills
Banana Split by Josi S. Kilpack
The Knaveheart's Curse by Adele Griffin
Nine by Andrzej Stasiuk
Whose Body by Dorothy L. Sayers