Authors: Professor Michael Hardt,Antonio Negri
Tags: #Philosophy, #Political, #Political Science, #General, #American Government
the other countries under Soviet control, the demand for higher
wages and greater freedom grew continuously along with the
rhythm ofmodernization. And just as in the capitalist countries,
there was defined a new figure oflabor power, which now expressed
enormous productive capacities on the basis ofa new development
R E S I S T A N C E , C R I S I S , T R A N S F O R M A T I O N
279
ofthe intellectual powers ofproduction. This new productive real-
ity, this living intellectual multitude, is what the Soviet leaders tried
to lock in the cages ofa disciplinary war economy (a war that was
continually conjured up rhetorically) and corral in the structures of
a socialist ideology oflabor and economic development, that is, a
socialist management ofcapital that no longer made any sense. The
Soviet bureaucracy was not able to construct the armory necessary
for the
postmodern
mobilization ofthe new labor power. It was
frightened by it, terrorized by the collapse of disciplinary regimes,
by the transformations of the Taylorized and Fordist subjects that
had previously animated production. This was the point where
the crisis became irreversible and, given the immobility ofthe
Brezhnevian hibernation, catastrophic.
What we find important was not so much the lack ofor the
offenses against the individual and formal freedoms of workers, but
rather the waste ofthe productive energy ofa multitude that had
exhausted the potential ofmodernity and now wanted to be liber-
ated from the socialist management of capitalist accumulation in
order to express a higher level ofproductivity. This repression and
this energy were the forces that, from opposite sides, made the
Soviet world collapse like a house ofcards. Glasnost and perestroika
certainly did represent a self-criticism of Soviet power and posed
the necessity ofa democratic passage as the condition for a renewed
productivity ofthe system, but they were employed too late and
too timidly to stop the crisis. The Soviet machine turned in on
itselfand ground to a halt, without the fuel that only new productive
subjectivities can produce. The sectors ofintellectual and immaterial
labor withdrew their consensus from the regime, and their exodus
condemned the system to death: death from the socialist victory of
modernization, death from the incapacity to use its effects and
surpluses, death from a definitive asphyxia that strangled the subjec-
tive conditions which demanded a passage to postmodernity.
3.4
P O S T M O D E R N I Z A T I O N , O R
T H E I N F O R M A T I Z A T I O N O F P R O D U C T I O N
Postmodernism is not something we can settle once and for all and
then use with a clear conscience. The concept, ifthere is one, has
to come at the end, and not at the beginning, ofour discussions
ofit.
Fredric Jameson
The good news from Washington is that every single person in
Congress supports the concept ofan information superhighway.
The bad news is that no one has any idea what that means.
Congressman Edward Markey
It has now become common to view the succession of
economic paradigms since the Middle Ages in three distinct mo-
ments, each defined by the dominant sector ofthe economy: a first
paradigm in which agriculture and the extraction ofraw materials
dominated the economy, a second in which industry and the manu-
facture of durable goods occupied the privileged position, and a third
and current paradigm in which providing services and manipulating
information are at the heart of economic production.1 The dominant
position has thus passed from primary to secondary to tertiary pro-
duction. Economic
modernization
involves the passage from the first paradigm to the second, from the dominance of agriculture to that
ofindustry. Modernization means industrialization. We might call
the passage from the second paradigm to the third, from the domina-
tion ofindustry to that ofservices and information, a process of
economic
postmodernization,
or better,
informatization.
P O S T M O D E R N I Z A T I O N
281
The most obvious definition and index ofthe shifts among
these three paradigms appear first in quantitative terms, in reference
either to the percentage ofthe population engaged in each ofthese
productive domains or to the percentage ofthe total value produced
by the various sectors ofproduction. The changes in employment
statistics in the dominant capitalist countries during the past one
hundred years do indeed indicate dramatic shifts.2 This quantitative
view, however, can lead to serious misunderstandings ofthese eco-
nomic paradigms. Quantitative indicators cannot grasp either the
qualitative
transformation in the progression from one paradigm to another or the
hierarchy
among the economic sectors in the context ofeach paradigm. In the process ofmodernization and the passage
toward the paradigm ofindustrial dominance, not only did agricul-
tural production decline quantitatively (both in percentage ofwork-
ers employed and in proportion ofthe total value produced), but
also, more important, agriculture itselfwas transf
ormed. When
agriculture came under the domination ofindustry, even when
agriculture was still predominant in quantitative terms, it became
subject to the social and financial pressures ofindustry, and moreover
agricultural production itselfwas industrialized. Agriculture, of
course, did not disappear; it remained an essential component of
modern industrial economies, but it was now a transformed, indus-
trialized agriculture.
The quantitative perspective also fails to recognize hierarchies
among national or regional economies in the global system, which
leads to all kinds ofhistorical misrecognitions, posing analogies
where none exist. From a quantitative perspective, for example,
one might assume a twentieth-century society with the majority
ofits labor force occupied in agriculture or mining and the majority
ofits value produced in these sectors (such as India or Nigeria) to
be in a position analogous to a society that existed sometime in the
past with the same percentage ofworkers or value produced in
those sectors (such as France or England). The historical illusion
casts the analogy in a dynamic sequence so that one economic
system occupies the same position or stage in a sequence ofdevelop-
282
P A S S A G E S O F P R O D U C T I O N
ment that another had held in a previous period, as ifall were
on the same track moving forward in line. From the qualitative
perspective, that is, in terms oftheir position in global power
relationships, however, the economies ofthese societies occupy
entirely incomparable positions. In the earlier case (France or En-
gland ofthe past), the agricultural production existed as the domi-
nant sector in its economic sphere, and in the later (twentieth-
century India or Nigeria), it is subordinated to industry in the world
system. The two economies are not on the same track but in
radically different and even divergent situations—of dominance and
subordination. In these different positions of hierarchy, a host of
economic factors is completely different—exchange relationships,
credit and debt relationships, and so forth.3 In order for the latter
economy to realize a position analogous to that ofthe former, it
would have to invert the power relationship and achieve a position
ofdominance in its contemporary economic sphere, as Europe did,
for example, in the medieval economy of the Mediterranean world.
Historical change, in other words, has to be recognized in terms
ofthe power relationships throughout the economic sphere.
Illusions of Development
The discourse ofeconomic
development,
which was imposed under
U.S. hegemony in coordination with the New Deal model in the
postwar period, uses such false historical analogies as the foundation
for economic policies. This discourse conceives the economic his-
tory ofall countries as following one single pattern ofdevelopment,
each at different times and according to different speeds. Countries
whose economic production is not presently at the level ofthe
dominant countries are thus seen as developing countries, with the
idea that ifthey continue on the path followed previously by the
dominant countries and repeat their economic policies and strate-
gies, they will eventually enjoy an analogous position or stage. The
developmental view fails to recognize, however, that the economies
ofthe so-called developed countries are defined not only by certain
quantitative factors or by their internal structures, but also and more
important by
their dominant position in the global system.
P O S T M O D E R N I Z A T I O N
283
The critiques ofthe developmentalist view that were posed
by underdevelopment theories and dependency theories, which
were born primarily in the Latin American and African contexts
in the 1960s, were useful and important precisely because they
emphasized the fact that the evolution of a regional or national
economic system depends to a large extent on its place within the
hierarchy and power structures ofthe capitalist world-system.4 The
dominant regions will continue to develop and the subordinate will
continue to underdevelop as mutually supporting poles in the global
power structure. To say that the subordinate economies do not
develop does not mean that they do not change or grow; it means,
rather, that
they remain subordinate in the global system
and thus never achieve the promised form of a dominant, developed economy. In
some cases individual countries or regions may be able to change
their position in the hierarchy, but the point is that, regardless of
who fills which position, the hierarchy remains the determining
factor.5
The theorists ofunderdevelopment themselves, however, also
repeat a similar illusion ofeconomic development.6 Summarizing
in schematic terms, we could say that their logic begins with two
valid historical claims but then draws from them an erroneous
conclusion. First, they maintain that, through the imposition of
colonial regimes and/or other forms of imperialist domination,
the underdevelopment ofsubordinated economies was created and
sustained by their integration into the global network ofdominant
capitalist economies, their partial articulation, and thus their real
and continuing dependence on those dominant economies. Second,
they claim that the dominant economies themselves had originally
developed their fully articulated and independent structures in rela-
tive isolation, with only limited interaction with other economies
and global networks.7
From these two more or less acceptable historical claims, how-
ever, they then deduce an invalid conclusion: ifthe developed
economies achieved full articulation in relative isolation and the
underdeveloped economies became disarticulated and dependent
through their integration into global networks, then a project for
284
P A S S A G E S O F P R O D U C T I O N
the relative isolation ofthe underdeveloped economies will result
in their development and full articulation. In other words, as an
alternative to the ‘ false development’’ pandered by the economists of
the dominant capitalist countries, the theorists ofunderdevelopment
promoted ‘‘real development,’’ which involves delinking an econ-
omy from its dependent relationships and articulating in relative
isolation an autonomous economic structure. Since this is how the
dominant economies developed, it must be the true path to escape
the cycle ofunderdevelopment. This syllogism, however, asks us
to believe that the laws ofeconomic development will somehow
transcend the differences of historical change.
The alternative notion ofdevelopment is based paradoxically
on the same historical illusion central to the dominant ideology of
development it opposes. The tendential realization ofthe world
market should destroy any notion that today a country or region
could isolate or delink itselffrom the global networks ofpower in
order to re-create the conditions ofthe past and develop as the
dominant capitalist countries once did. Even the dominant countries
are now dependent on the global system; the interactions ofthe
world market have resulted in a generalized disarticulation ofall
economies. Increasingly, any attempt at isolation or separation will
mean only a more brutal kind ofdomination by the global system,
a reduction to powerlessness and poverty.
Informatization
The processes ofmodernization and industrialization transformed
and redefined all the elements ofthe social plane. When agriculture
was modernized as industry, the farm progressively became a factory,
with all ofthe factory’s discipline, technology, wage relations, and